Deregulation Essay

Cheap Custom Writing Service

The erosion or abandonment of formal regulations by legislative means is known as deregulation. Formerly regulated industries—transportation, electric utilities, gas utilities, telecommunications, and financial markets—share   certain   characteristics   that   made them candidates for regulation, and in transitioning to deregulation they share a common set of problems.

Wherever  they have appeared  around  the  world, regulatory  systems  were  not  the  result  of strategic planning, but represented a reaction to financial, economic, and political crises. The airline industry,  the steel  industry,  and  every other  industry  have been subject  to  direct  and  indirect  regulation.  Indirect regulation dealing with the environment, work safety, product quality, truth in advertising, and similar issues affects all firms. The fundamental  reasons for regulating the banking industry lie in the key role banks play in the efficient functioning of the economic system and in the conduct of an effective monetary policy, as well as protection for depositors and monetary stability.

In a Brookings Institution study, Martha Derthick and Paul Quirk acknowledge that government regulation had long been rationalized  as a way of guaranteeing service to the public by industries  having the character  of public utilities and as a means  of protecting the public from monopoly pricing practices, including the destructive competition that was said to lead to the creation of monopolies. However, the regulatory agencies had instead sheltered  the regulated industries from competition  and fostered very costly inefficiencies. Long a target of experts in administrative law, public administration, and political science, who found much fault with their structure  and procedures, by the 1960s the regulatory commissions  had become  a target  also of economists,  who  attacked their purposes by undertaking  to show that the social costs of regulation far outweigh the benefits.

The notion  of government  regulation  as a profit seeking enterprise in which self-interested groups and individuals seek to gain competitive advantage and in which the regulator is captured by the regulated is the basic argument of Chicago School economists George Stigler and Sam Peltzman. Deregulation suddenly changes the game of market competition, threatening the long-held advantage of dominant  large firms and opening the way for new entrants.

The United  States

Deregulation  has  been  the  global  trend  since  the late 1970s and early 1980s. In the United States, the energy,  airline,  trucking,  and  telephone   industries were  deregulated  in  1978, 1980, and  1982. Under strict  federal regulation  since 1954, the  natural-gas industry began to exhibit shortages in the late 1960s. By the 1970s, producers  were unable or unwilling to supply as much  gas as customers  wanted  to buy at the regulated price. In 1978 Congress set a timetable for deregulation  of most natural-gas  prices. By 1985, when all gas discovered after 1976 was freed from federal price regulations, gas prices began a steep plunge. After  that,  federal  regulators   began  to  transform natural-gas  pipelines into “open access” transporters of gas from various producers. Deregulation not only lowered prices for consumers, but also improved the quality of service by removing the threat of artificially created shortages.

Before 1978, both  the  maximum  and  minimum fares for air travel were set by the Civil Aeronautics Board (CAB). The CAB began to loosen its regulations in the mid-1970s. In 1978, Congress passed legislation to abolish the CAB within six years, open up the industry to new competitors,  and eliminate government-set fares. Under regulation, intercity airline routes were served by one, two, or three carriers, all charging  the same fare; after deregulation  both  the number  of carriers  and  their  prices  became  highly competitive, including such practices as restricted discounts, promotional  fares, reduced off-peak fares, and premium services.

Federal regulation  of interstate  trucking  began in 1935. Throughout  the  1960s and  early 1970s, economic research showed that trucking rates would be far lower in a competitive marketplace. In response to the growing opposition to interstate  regulation, Congress passed legislation in 1980 that virtually deregulated the trucking industry. Deregulation meant shipping rates could be negotiated by individual shippers and carriers, with prices and services tailored to the shippers’ needs. While big shippers  were in the strongest bargaining position, smaller shippers often needed to consolidate shipments to get a good rate.

The collapse of the merged Penn Central rail line in the mid-1970s prompted  a major push to deregulate and  transform  the  railroad  sector.  Congress  passed a bill in 1976 that  allowed railroads  to  merge  and to  abandon  unprofitable  routes; in  1980, Congress deregulated  rates for some commodities.  Gradually, rate  deregulation  extended  to  about  90 percent  of rail traffic. Rail deregulation  led to improved service, improving delivery time by 30 percent.

The first movement  toward competitive  long-distance telephone  service came not from Washington policymakers  but  from  the  entrepreneurial  efforts of Microwave Communications, Inc. (MCI). In 1969 MCI  won  federal  permission  to  begin  competing with the  AT&T monopoly  to provide  “private-line” long-distance  to companies,  but did not receive the go-ahead  to  enter  the  ordinary  long-distance  market for businesses or residences.  MCI clandestinely began to offer standard long-distance to businesses in 1974 without  authorization by the Federal Communications Commission  (FCC). The FCC tried to stop MCI, but lost in federal court. The FCC did authorize competition  in telephone equipment,  a move ratified by the courts in 1977.

As the pressure for competition in the long-distance and  telephone-equipment industries  began  to  heat up, the federal government challenged AT&T’s use of its monopoly on local telephone  service to compete unfairly. Its legal actions finally led to a consent decree in 1982 that split “Ma Bell” into seven local telephone companies  and a separate  long-distance  and equipment business that retained the AT&T name. Equipment prices fell by 6 to 7 percent a year between 1972 and  1987. Competition has  also  improved  quality dramatically and led to the introduction of many new devices and services. Deregulation  meant  telephone users found that they could shop for bargains in long distance  service. Whereas  American  Telephone  and Telegraph  (AT&T) and  the  affiliates and  “independents” in its network were at one time the sole suppliers of long distance service, competitors now offered service at rates substantially below AT&T’s.

While  the  history  of U.S. financial  deregulation began in 1973, the period 1982–90 saw the disintegration  of the savings and loan insurance  fund and a sizable portion  of the  thrift  industry  and  regulator-sponsored deregulation  that  provided  increased earning opportunities, and risk, for surviving thrifts and commercial banks.

Japan, Russia, And China

By the early 1980s many capitalist governments reduced government interference in the marketplace, prompting  increased  competition.  Japan’s telecommunications  monopoly,  NT&T,  was deregulated  in 1985,  and  European  deregulation   followed  in  the mid-1990s.

Before the collapse of communism,  governments in most command economies exercised tight control over prices and output  through  state planning, prohibiting private enterprises  from operating  in most sectors of the economy, severely restricting foreign direct investment,  and limiting international trade.  Deregulation involved removing price controls, thereby allowing market forces to set prices. Laws regulating the establishment  and  operation  of private  enterprises  were abolished,  and  restrictions  on  foreign  direct  investment and trade were relaxed or removed.

In Russia deregulation  of prices was imposed through  a presidential  decree of December  3, 1991, “Measures to Liberalize Prices,” which solemnly declared that “on January 2, 1992, [the Russian Federation would undertake]  the basic transition  to free (market)  prices and tariffs, formed  under  the influence of demand and supply” on producer  goods, consumer  goods, services, and labor. By the end of 1993, only two sectors, energy and agriculture,  were regulated. The state monopoly  on foreign trade  had effectively been abolished in late 1986, when various branch ministries were given the right to pursue foreign trade independently.

Deregulation  in China  went  through  two phases. From 1980 until 1993, government began the partial or total deregulation of public sector enterprises, increasing the  autonomy  of state-owned  enterprises  under the “contract responsibility system,” under which state-owned  assets were leased out.  By 1987 over 27,000 state-owned enterprises had been leased out.

The second stage in China’s deregulation began in 1993 when the  Central  Committee  of the  Chinese Communist Party  issued  the  so-called  Resolution on Several Issues Concerning  the Establishment  of a Socialist Market Economy, which established a 50 point  agenda for bold economic  reform,  including placing the assets of 1,000 large state-owned  enterprises under  the supervision of new asset management  companies; transferring  control  of 100 large and medium-sized state-owned enterprises to shareholding companies, among other reforms. The plan was stalled by the 1997 East Asia financial crisis, but has resumed.

India

In mixed economies, the role of the state was more limited, but in certain sectors the state set prices, owned businesses, limited private enterprise, restricted investment  by foreigners and restricted  international trade—alongside  an  active, growing  private  sector. India is a good example of a mixed economy that is currently deregulating a large portion of its economy. Deregulation in India has involved reforming the industrial  licensing system that  made  it difficult to establish private enterprises, opening areas that were once closed to the private sector, removing limits on foreign ownership of Indian assets, and lowering barriers to international trade.

Like China,  India  has  also followed a sequenced deregulation  pattern  since the  mid-1970s,  when  the central government proposed a reduction in the number  of industries  reserved  exclusively for the  public sector. India’s public sector undertakings are the equivalent of state-owned  enterprises, often state monopolies in core or strategic industries,  which are the sole suppliers of steel, coal, and oil to industry. A significant percentage (over 70 percent) of the total employment in the industrial  sector  is in these enterprises; other public sector undertakings exist in noncore or nonstrategic areas, such as hotels and tourism.

Major  institutional  reforms  in the  public sector were announced  in July 1991 with  the  passage of the New Industrial  Policy, which gradually reduced India’s  extensive  industrial   licensing  regime.  The New Industrial  Policy also encouraged  reforms  of public enterprises in order to make them better performers and more competitive. Beginning August 7, 1996, the  Ministry  of Industry  moved quickly and aggressively to  select public  sector  enterprises  for disinvestment.  India’s economic  reforms  have continued  despite  an apparent  trend  in minority  governing coalitions at the center.

Latin America

During the 1980s, many developing countries entered upon a process of deregulation  in which government controls  over market  operations,  resource  allocation, and capital flows were removed  or loosened, a consequence of the oil price shock and the ensuing economic crisis, which forced fundamental  reorientation of development  strategies across countries  and thrust the issue of financial reform  onto  the policy agenda. Coupled with the economic crisis was a cross-national ideological crusade against state interventionism supported by the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and major industrial powers to expand the role of market forces. In Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay, deregulation  included  steps to privatize state-owned banks, free interest rates, and eliminate restrictions on capital flows. Contrary to what had been expected by proponents of financial liberalization, reform efforts in the Southern Cone ended in chaotic financial markets, massive inflation, and worsening external imbalances, leading to  the  reversal of the  liberalization  process.

The disastrous  outcomes  raised  the  question  about the appropriate  economic and institutional  conditions under which financial reform strategies should be designed and implemented.

Unlike  their  Latin  American  counterparts, however, the East Asian newly industrializing  economies (NIEs) took a cautious and gradual line of action, until the second half of 1997, when many of the East Asian NIEs were struck by the worst-ever financial crisis in the postwar economic history of the region.

Indonesia, Korea, And Thailand

Farrukh Iqbal and William James note that until the mid-1980s,  Indonesia  lagged behind  its East Asian neighbors  in deregulating  or  liberalizing trade  and investment  policy, due  in  part  to  reliable  primary sector (mostly oil) revenues. During the latter half of the 1980s, Indonesia made substantial  reforms in its trade, investment, and financial regimes: Tariffs were cut, nontariff barriers were reduced, a duty-drawback system was introduced for export  activities, a complex investment  licensing system was replaced  by a much simpler and relatively short “negative list,” foreign investment  regulations were significantly eased, credit  ceilings and interest  rate controls  were abolished, and entry into the banking system was made substantially easier.

Like many of their neighboring  economies, Korea and  Thailand opted  for a gradual  pattern  of policy responses,  particularly  in the initial stages of financial reform. Korea adopted  a gradual and piecemeal approach  to  the  liberalization  of interest  rates  and credit controls, but gave greater freedom to nonbank financial institutions,  such as finance companies, merchant  banking corporations,  and securities firms, to mobilize savings and develop the financial system.

In Thailand, the authorities  placed more emphasis on expanding the role of the banking system in service diversification and financial development.  Thailand, which had  maintained  relatively relaxed  controls over its external  financial transactions,  further deregulated the remaining controls while liberalizing the domestic financial market.

Effects

Sarkis Khoury sees the deregulated international financial environment as having been developed partially by design, but largely as a result of the dynamic market forces that  produced  more  competitive  markets all over the world and “leaner and meaner” financial institutions,  with consolidation  through  mergers and acquisitions reducing the number of firms and increasing competition among the larger, remaining  institutions. Khoury predicts that competition will only continue to increase as markets become more global and as new, aggressive entities come into the market. The Japanese firms which were once nowhere  on the list of prominent financial institutions  are now dominant in the world of finance. The Koreans and the Chinese have become major players. European financial institutions have streamlined their operations, and improved their product  mix and their resource base in order to better compete more successfully in a united Europe.

While governments  have taken a proactive strategy to deregulate  their  industries  and  financial markets, to open trade and foreign direct investment  in order to stimulate  sluggish economies,  the permanency  of the changes is still in doubt. A severe worldwide economic setback could prove a real test. Again, it must be emphasized  that regulation  is cyclical and potentially reversible. As Barbara Emadi-Coffin argues in her study of deregulation  and  governance,  while deregulation implies the roll-back of the state, in fact, deregulation and the establishment  of free trade zones have necessitated extensive government regulation and subsidy.

A financial crisis in 2008 had its roots in the GrammLeach-Bliley Act (1999), a bank deregulation  bill, that swept away a Depression-era law known as Glass-Steagall. Gramm-Leach-Bliley tore down the separation of banks doing risky investments  from those doing basic lending. In addition, some investment banking houses make  risky bets  that  went  awry in 2008. American policy makers and regulators let Wall Street recklessly invest  in  the  context  of extremely  inflated  housing prices (a bubble). Also to blame was the Commodity Futures Modernization Act, which freed the derivatives market and enabled banks to become more aggressive in their mortgage investments.

Bibliography:   

  1. Anders Aslund, How Russia Became a Market Economy (Brookings Institution, 1995);
  2. Sean Barrett, Deregulation and the Airline Business in Europe (Routledge, 2009);
  3. Martha Derthick and Paul J. Quirk, The Politics of Deregulation (Brookings Institution, 1985);
  4. Barbara Emadi-Coffin, Rethinking International Organization: Deregulation and Global Governance (Routledge,  2002);
  5. John Hood,  “Dividends  of Deregulation,”  Policy Review (v.84, 1997);
  6. Farrukh Iqbal and William E. James, Deregulation and Development in Indonesia (Praeger, 2002);
  7. Sarkis J. Khoury, The Deregulation of the World Financial Markets: Myths, Realities, and Impact (Quorum Books, 1990);
  8. David Leonhardt, “Washington’s Invisible Hand,” New York Times (September 26, 2008);
  9. Paul W. MacAvoy, The Unsustainable Costs of Partial Deregulation (Yale University Press, 2007);
  10. John R. Meyer et al., The Transition to Deregulation: Developing Economic Standards  for Public Policies (Quorum  Books, 1991);
  11. Tom W. Norwood, Deregulation Knockouts. Round Two (Airways International Inc., 2006);
  12. Jeffrey Worsham,  Other  People’s Money: Policy Change, Congress, and  Bank  Regulation (Westview  Press, 1997);
  13. Xiaoke Zhang, The Changing Politics of Finance in Korea and Thailand: From Deregulation to Debacle (Routledge, 2002).

This example Deregulation Essay is published for educational and informational purposes only. If you need a custom essay or research paper on this topic please use our writing services. EssayEmpire.com offers reliable custom essay writing services that can help you to receive high grades and impress your professors with the quality of each essay or research paper you hand in.

See also:

ORDER HIGH QUALITY CUSTOM PAPER


Always on-time

Plagiarism-Free

100% Confidentiality

Special offer!

GET 10% OFF WITH 24START DISCOUNT CODE