Firms, as societal entities, operate in particular economic, political, and legal environments. The legal environment is a result of legislative intervention by the government (state) and the positive practices that are recognized and sanctioned by the positive law. Historically, the legal environment has usually been nationally defined, although scholars have tried to group legal systems into various groups, based on their similarities and dissimilarities.
A student of this topic would usually argue that there are two basic groups of legal systems, which traditionally have been opposed: the Anglo-Saxon (Anglo-American) model and the continental European law. However, although both main systems of law may have their distinctive features listed, in fact there are far too many convergences in recent times. In the past the common law (Anglo-Saxon) model would be predominantly based on the precedents, and the continental European law would be primarily based on the codifications. But, there is ever-increasing legislative activity in the Anglo-Saxon countries, with a number of codifications taking place as judiciary may uphold the consistency of court practice. In either system, a judge may take a stance to create a precedent, but the sources of precedent would differ significantly.
Anglo-Saxon Versus Continental European Models
Growing empirical literature has attempted to prove the overall superiority of the Anglo-Saxon model. Although it is evident that economies of Anglo-Saxon countries may be doing comparatively better than the others in the long run, it is not empirically corroborated that the growth sustained over a period of time may be directly attributed to the features of the legal system (legal environment). Legal systems, although they may be classified into larger groups, are basically heavily influenced by national colors and experiences of legal development, especially in revolutionary environments (when there is abrupt change in the development).
Scholars studying legal environments would focus more, nowadays, on judiciary independence from the state and the politicians. It is believed that if the judiciary protects consistently property rights, even from the state, the results of development will be better, and in the case-law system, judges historically have been more prone to uphold the sanctity of private property rights. Ex post judging is far better in responding to local information, rather than the application of abstract law, regulating the principles.
However, increasingly the common law countries are resorting to promulgating laws and codices, in order to better capture different areas of law. In the United States, the Uniform Commercial Code (UCC) is probably the best example. The growth in legislative activity may also be seen as a sign of upcoming struggle between judiciary and legislative power for predominant societal influence. Most recently the discussion on “political delegation” would suggest that it is necessary to subsume, at least formally, all institutions of the state to the highest democratically elected body in the country (assembly, parliament, etc.), although that body is controlled exclusively by the politicians. The literature has also defined a common law system as one in which judges exercise discretion to decide cases in independent and/or adaptive lawmaking ways, while in continental European countries the state would control judicial outcomes and the content of law as well.
The basic premise of change between the two wider legal groups has been the perception as to what extent the judicial practice may influence the future legal decision taken by the court. It is a fact that in Anglo-Saxon countries precedents are a source of law and they have to be regarded in the future when the act is required in a similar situation. However, although in the continental European legal system judiciary practice is not a formal source of law, judges take into consideration the prior practice in order to ensure consistency in acting in the court and the country.
In comparative law, the literature is quite often focused on a set of five parameters, like (1) judicial incentives; (2) exogenous legal human capital; (3) the processing of litigant information into judicial error– reducing legal human capital; (4) the cost of producing evidence and legal arguments; and (5) the penalties (damages) levied in adjudication.
Judicial incentives may be influenced by the way their independence is defined. Often in the analysis judicial independence features highly, especially as it is believed to be an important feature of the Anglo-Saxon model, which contributed to its better results. In the U.S. model, over 80 percent of serving judges are subject to some kind of election, reelection, or recall voting. But even in the United States the upper echelons of judiciary are dependent on politicians who decide on their promotion to the highest offices. Similarly, in the continental European countries, the government may have a strong say in appointment of judges, especially in the case of higher courts. However, the very path of professional progression differs between European (especially French) and U.S. judges. In Europe, judges are often career civil servants, who have opted for the judiciary profession almost immediately upon graduation from the university; in the United States, judges are appointed from among practicing lawyers who have had more than 10 years of professional experience.
Comparative analysis of independence has shown more than a puzzle—judges should be independent, but the question is from whom? And, if one is independent, does it mean that he or she is also unbiased (objective)? Often it is assumed that judges, if not appointed by the government directly, will be critical of the government and look at the breaking of law made by the government in an unbiased manner. However, empirical research does not corroborate this claim. Some judges are more independent and unbiased in the way they operate than others, but it cannot be generalized as to what contributes to that.
Another important feature is the relationship between precedents and statutes. Anglo-Saxon law is believed to be based on a set of more or less harmonious precedents (stare decisis), while the continental European legal practices are based on the interpretation of law and the application of the abstract legal (statutory) rule to a concrete situation. However, even in the latter case there is a high level of consistency in judiciary practices, as the higher courts have the right of cassation and therefore for the performance of judges it is important that their decisions not be annulled and/or modified by the higher court. Therefore, even in the continental European legal systems, court practices are consistent, that is, jurisprudence constante.
At the far end, the issue is primarily behavioral— whether the judges will be expansive or rather conservative (narrow) in their apprehension of laws. Some recent empirical research has clearly shown consistency of judicial behavior across various systems. However, de jure legal practice is not a formal source of law in continental European legal systems, but, as already pointed out, will be seriously considered in the process of application of law. In both systems the vast majority of judges will opt not to rock the boat.
Career Paths
Another important feature of these two main groups of legal systems that has already been mentioned is the career path in either of the systems. In the continental European system the judges follow the clear career path from a judicial trainee in lower courts to the position in the higher courts, including the Supreme Court. Although there are mid-career entrants from the legal profession, it is fairly rare to have those transfers. However, transfers from the judge’s chair to the bench are more frequent, especially in the situations where there is a public distrust in the judicial system or endemic economic crisis. There are attempts in both systems to objectivize the appointment of judges and base their direct promotion on merit. In France, a complex panel decides on the appointments of judges, and the panel is chaired by the president and consists of the corresponding ministers and others, mainly appointments from the judiciary.
In contrast, in both the United States and Canada, judges are appointed only after a somewhat long and distinguished professional career, usually as a practicing lawyer. In either system the politicians are still in a position to influence the appointment of new judges/ justices, with more or less interference, However, it seems that the principles of political delegation are gaining good soil, and it is to expect that judges will be more often appointed by “independent” panels, and their promotion will be based upon their performance results and personal zeal to succeed. One feature certainly remains to be noted. In the Anglo-Saxon practice there is a well-established process where judges are exposed to collegial referee procedures (peer review).
Courts
In various jurisdictions the courts are organized in their own way—for instance, in France, specialization for particular court cases (administrative court, family court, etc.), while generalization is more specific for the United States, although the situation is changing. Nevertheless, there are opportunities to reconcile these two factions. In the United States, it is believed that appellate specialization has, in fact, led to a somewhat biased position of the court, especially in patent cases, where this specialization in the Federal Circuit has led to an overly pro-patent orientation. More generalized courts may be more active in the competition for cases, that is, attracting jurisdiction and therefore ensuring more effective and efficient behavior under the outside influence.
Further on, the systems differ in how they handle court-released information. It is possible to have an environment in which all the interested parties disclose much information or simply feed the judge with the information he or she may need. A judge who is more under (immediate) public scrutiny may behave in a manner that he or she will carefully weigh the need for changes in the existent practices before committing to the change in the practice and new precedent being deliberated. In contrast, the judge or a Supreme Court justice who is not known to the broader public may be more enticed to make a decision that would depart from the current practice, especially if the welfare loss or gain is a zero-sum game.
Procedural elements are also very important in contrasting legal regimes. Namely, procedural elements do influence judicial incentives and direct engagement in the procedure before the court. An Anglo-Saxon, i.e., Anglo-American, model of adversarial justice requires a judge to be an unbiased referee as both sides present the facts and try to establish the truth. The judge in turn is not expected to actively look for other evidence. In contrast, the continental European model requires a judge to be an active participant in the procedure and to actively seek truth, and may require the presentation of facts in order to establish proof.
Similarly, the use of jurors differs between the systems, although in principle jurors are used almost exclusively in criminal cases. In the Anglo-Saxon model the jury decides guilt, while the judge as a professional does the sentencing, usually well after the case before the jury has been completed. In the continental European model, jurors often sit with the presiding judge as a member of the panel and decide on the major issues by majority vote. Even the concept of the jury has changed over time. In the past jurors were chosen because they were familiar with the case, and nowadays the court looks for full impartiality of jurors.
Legal environments/legal systems differ from country to country and to a large extent they may have shown some signs of convergence, but in fact they remain largely national, belonging more or less consistently to the legal groups we have outlined here.
Bibliography:
- Jeffrey F. Beatty and Susan S. Samuelson, Legal Environment (Cenage/South-Western College Publishers, 2007);
- Beck, A. Demirgüç-Kunt, and R. Levine, “Law and Finance: Why Does Legal Origin Matter?” Journal of Comparative Economics (v.31/4, 2003);
- Ash Demirguc-Kunt, Inessa Love, and Vojislav Maksimovic, “Business Environment and the Incorporation Decision,” Journal of Banking and Finance (v.30/11, 2006);
- K. Hadfield, “The Levers of Legal Design: Institutional Determinants of the Quality of Law,” Journal of Comparative Economics (v.36/1, 2007);
- La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Salines, C. Pop-Eleches, and A Shleifer, “Judicial Checks and Balances,” Journal of Political Economy (v.112, 2004);
- La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Salines, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, “Law and Finance,” Journal of Political Economy (v.106, 1998);
- La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Salines, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, “Legal Determinants of External Finance,” Journal of Finance (v.52, 1997);
- Min-Dong Paul Lee, “A Review of the Theories of Corporate Social Responsibility: Its Evolutionary Paths and the Road Ahead,” International Journal of Management Reviews (v.10/1, 2008).
This example Legal Environments Essay is published for educational and informational purposes only. If you need a custom essay or research paper on this topic please use our writing services. EssayEmpire.com offers reliable custom essay writing services that can help you to receive high grades and impress your professors with the quality of each essay or research paper you hand in.