Nationalization Essay

Cheap Custom Writing Service

Government  ownership of an industry or a formerly private company is known as nationalization. By far the more frequent of the two phenomena is government ownership  of an  industry.  Although  some  authors, such as Lars Bengtsson, have argued that  choice of industries is random, nationalized industries typically are those that government considers to be fundamental to national security (from oil to media) or national income (based on a natural resource that may also be a wasting resource), as well as those that are particularly attractive to foreign direct investment. According to Bengtsson, a nationalized  industry can be viewed as  a  governmental  hierarchy,  whereas  an  industry with a strong  governmental  organization  that  buys, sells, and/or  competes with private actors is called a governmental  market  system. The government  can also govern a market with only private actors through regulations, via a regulated market system.

Amy Chua discussed a different class of nationalization in developing economies, wherein the purpose is discrimination against an economically dominant ethnic minority. Here, market processes of competition and rule of law are manipulated to benefit certain ethnic constituents and to disadvantage others; little or no attempt  is made to justify this action in terms of socialist or communist  ideology. She cited the ethnically targeted nationalizations  and confiscations in postcolonial Burma, Indonesia, Kenya, Malaysia, Pakistan, the Philippines,  Sri Lanka, Thailand, Uganda, South Africa, and Zimbabwe.

Although  the primary focus of this essay is government  nationalization  of industry for issues of security, income, state building, or public policy, not nationalization  to disadvantage an ethnic  minority, the expropriation of private property is very often a consequence.

Precedents in International Law

In  his  study  of  nationalization  in  Latin  America, David Schneider man  noted  that constitutional rules once expressly enabled state intervention in the market to redistribute  wealth through  rules permitting the expropriation or nationalization of property, subject, for example, to the  provision  of “appropriate” compensation,  which protected host country governments from the external pressures generated  by foreign economic power. In the 1990s, this type of state capitalism fell into disfavor, and the countries of Latin America mostly abandoned the constitutional design mandating public control of the economy or enabling nationalization of key economic sectors.

Today, both expropriation of property and nationalization  are  prohibited  unless  they  are  for a public  purpose,   nondiscriminatory,  and  accompanied by the payment  of “prompt, adequate,  and effective compensation” that  is fully realizable and  transferable. This perspective  is embodied  in international law. In a famous case, the Iran–United States Claims Tribunal—created to resolve the  crisis between  the Islamic Republic of Iran and the United States arising out of the detention  of 52 U.S. nationals  at the U.S. Embassy in Tehran and the subsequent  freeze of Iranian assets by the United  States—it was found that property rights must be respected and that compensation  must  be paid when the alien owner of those rights  is deprived  of them  by acts attributable  to a state. Although a revolution does not by itself create liability, neither  a revolution  nor any other  changed political, economic,  or social circumstances  can be invoked to avoid liability for deprivation  of an alien’s property that is attributable  to the state.

Government’s Role In Economic

Growth Despite the ubiquity of government,  government  as an actor in national  economic  growth and development has been largely ignored by international business theorists. Government’s importance to economic growth was addressed by Bengtsson, who argued that even in many  traditionally  capitalist  countries,  the public sector (involving both national and local governments) accounts for one-third to one-half of GNP. Hence, government  is an actor in the economy as a whole, having a substantial influence over the governance structures  employed through its right of enacting laws. In fact, the government  is a more powerful agent of economic activity than any other single agent in most countries, whether their economies are capitalist, mixed, or planned.

In Storm over the Multinationals, Raymond Vernon  viewed the  activities of companies  expanding into multiple international jurisdictions  as a source of new complications  for national policies and programs affecting job creation, inequitable income distribution  among classes and regions, the availability of scarce supplies, the functioning  of local markets, tax  revenue,  consumer  safety, environmental protection,  and national  security. Writing  at the same time as Vernon and Maurice Bye, George Stigler saw the government regulator as an ineffective functionary, held  hostage  by the  more-moneyed, far more strategic regulated firm. Although international business  theorists  have largely ignored  the  role of government,  a few—such as Vernon, Bye, and Edith Penrose—have examined the public policy implications of government  action, including  the decision to nationalize.

Dynamics  Of Sharing  Oil Revenue

In her article “In Profit Sharing Between Producing Countries  and  Oil Companies  in the  Middle  East,” Penrose explored the economic questions involved in the sharing of oil revenue between the oil companies and the producing  countries—two  interested  parties that  stand  to gain from bargaining. One of the parties invests capital to start  the industry  and runs it; the other supplies the raw material, which is a wasting asset. Both parties are interested in promoting the most  profitable long-run  expansion  of the industry, but  the producing  countries’ governments  are concerned  with  their  own  oil production,  and  the  oil companies are concerned with investing in the countries from which they can expect the highest returns. Looking at Penrose’s indices of profitability and dividend payout for the oil majors from 1954 to 1966, one can see an increasing loss of profits paid out to foreign investors through dividends. While profits continued to grow, benefiting the majors, the loss of income to the  producing  countries  made the  case for government action to ensure profit sharing.

Penrose  argued  that  the  proportion of its profit that  a company is willing to give up depends  on its estimate of the cost of meeting the government’s final demands  compared  with the cost of resisting them, up to the point  where the loss in either  case makes the business unprofitable. Conversely, a government’s demands  depend  on the  loss that  it believes it can inflict on the  company  by not  giving or by canceling the concession under negotiation—that is, on its estimate  of the value of the concession  to the company—or on the amount  that it thinks the company is prepared  to give up to avert political disturbances and maintain political goodwill. The latter alternative applies in the  case of negotiations  with a company that is already established in a monopolistic  position in the country and in circumstances in which the government  cannot run the industry.

For an established oil company, the cost of acquiescing to the government’s demands is the additional profit lost in one form or another and the future profits expected. But the cost of resistance is not necessarily the loss of the concession (as it might be in the case of new concession agreements), for the company is in  a strong  position  to  precipitate  an  economic crisis, which may drive the negotiating  government out of office. In fact, the company itself need take no positive action, which would force the government to risk political action, arousing the populace against the oil companies, condoning or inciting political harassment, or threatening nationalization on terms unacceptable to the company—steps that, once taken, are not easy to retreat from.

Granting  Concessions Versus Nationalizing

If the  economy  of  a  country  has  become  heavily dependent on the continuance of oil revenue, and the government  cannot  run the industry, an existing oil company, if it has a virtual monopoly or acts in concert with other companies, is in an extremely strong position vis-à-vis any single government. The progressive economic deterioration following the cessation of oil revenue is likely to cause greater political difficulties for the government, its eventual repudiation,  and the substitution of a government  pledged to reestablish the flow of oil revenue.

If the oil companies compete for a concession, the share of profits offered to the government rises to the point  where the company  obtaining  the concession retains only normal profit—the amount of anticipated profit that would just induce the company to enter or continue  to invest in the oil industry of the country. In this circumstance,  the government  would be able to extract nearly the full value of the concession from each company.

If the government can run the industry and obtain revenue not significantly below the revenue it previously obtained  from the companies,  it is in a good position  to nationalize.  Forcing the  foreign companies out completely would not be to the country’s economic advantage, because the country would lose the indirect  advantages  of increased  rate of innovation; freer  flow of technical  information,  leading  to  the more rapid application of advanced technology; and a greater supply of technical and managerial personnel. In calculating the advantages of nationalization,  the government  should take into consideration the alternative product  that could have been produced  by its resources, had they not been directed into oil production,  including  lost  productivity,  foreign  exchange, and tax revenue.

Impact of Nongovernment Forces

Bye, the French structural economist, investigated the impact on the world economy of the interplay of flows and forces depending neither entirely on government nor  on firms. Like Penrose,  he focused on wasting assets (oil and mines). Bye warned that given the differential planning horizons of foreign investing firms and  national  governments,  the  latter  cannot  delay public welfare for long-term growth gains that might materialize only after the resource is depleted; it must fund social programs in the short term via taxes, tariffs, and other actions directed  at what he called the “large multi-territorial unit.” Governments, therefore, have an incentive to drive up extraction  revenue  to the point where the company obtaining  the concession retains only normal profit, which is the amount of anticipated profit just sufficient to induce the company to enter or continue to invest in the country’s oil industry. In these circumstances, the government can extract  nearly the full value of the concession  from each company.

Alternatively, if the government can run the industry itself (nationalize it) and obtain revenue not significantly below the  revenue  it previously obtained from the companies, it is in an extremely strong position with respect to established oil companies.

It should  be noted  that  nationalization could  be done without inhibiting technological progress if the government-owned firm were able to do technology licensing deals or call in consultants.  Indeed,  given that rival firms stand to make money from technology licensing or consulting services, there is scope for playing them off against one another.

Subsidizing Small Firms

In her introduction to The Large International Firm in Developing Countries Penrose quoted Bye:

The mutual relations of large firms within one and the same industry … have an impact on the world economy  which  is at least as important as that which the theory of the market  assigns to factor proportion

and observed that his remark “applies with full force to [the oil] this industry … ” The international petroleum industry is dominated  by a few large sellers, but operating  in the  interstices  of the  oil market  are a group of smaller independents, whose activities have a significant influence on the industry. These smaller firms exist largely because of government  action. Exploration  is expensive, and  small firms naturally operate  at a cost disadvantage  in this area; government  subsidies and regulations, however, can create artificial but effective barriers to monopoly by making it impossible for foreign firms to operate  without  a domestic partner.

Investment In Developing Countries

Thomas  Andersson’s study  of multinational investment   in  developing  countries   suggested  that   the endeavors  of many  developing  countries  to  obtain benefits such as direct investment, reduced tax rates, and free profit repatriation further  reduce their foreign exchange earnings from direct investment, particularly  because  multinational enterprises  tend to repatriate  funds rather  than  reinvest  in troubled economies. This situation increases the attractiveness of nationalization,  the risk of which again hampers direct investment and other benefits. Since the 1970s, however, nationalization has been in decline.

Andersson’s investigation cited access to inexpensive borrowing,  a fall in commodity  prices, and the increasingly  negative  impact  on  direct  investment from continuing  the practice of nationalization after most   other   countries   had  stopped.   Nevertheless, the developing countries’ need for foreign exchange remains critical, as those countries have accumulated multibillion-dollar  debts, and exports to the industrialized economies have been squeezed by import quotas and other kinds of protectionism.

Direct investment is increasingly viewed as a favorable source of foreign capital, employment  opportunities, and an increase in output  and exports. Hence, host country policies have become more benevolent than ever, and the recent investment revival in developing countries is expected to continue over the next decade. Increasing wealth, privatization, and government  openness  to  foreign  direct  investment  (FDI) have led to increased private investment in previously nationalized businesses.

Economies In Transition

According  to  UNCTAD,  FDI  inflows  to  developing countries  and economies in transition  (the latter comprising southeastern Europe and CIS) rose by 16 percent and 41 percent, respectively, in 2007 to a new record  of $98 billion. Whereas  resource-rich countries such as Kazakhstan received more than in 2006, the privatization of formerly state-owned  enterprises drove FDI toward southeastern Europe.

FDI inflows to Africa, an estimated $36 billion, were supported  by a continuing  boom in global commodity markets, but new inbound  FDI took place in the banking industry. Egypt, Morocco, and South Africa were the main beneficiaries of FDI inflows.

In Nigeria, the government  divested 51 percent of its stake in NITEL, the country’s telecom operator  in 2006, to Transcorp  for $500 million in the hope that privatization would turn around its performance  and improve  services. Now  the  government  is seeking a new investor to acquire 27 percent  of Transcorp’s share in NITEL and to buy another  24 percent of the state’s remaining 41 percent share and take control of the company.

Since its establishment  in 2002, the Kosovo Trust Agency (KTA) has  sold  a  significant  share  of the country’s state-owned  enterprises  through  spin-off and liquidation methods. As of November 2007, KTA administered   about   650  state-owned   enterprises; about 320 companies were privatized and about 110 firms placed in liquidation.

 

Bibliography:   

  1. George H. Aldrich, “What Constitutes a Compensable  Taking of Property?  The Decisions of the Iran–United States Claims Tribunal,” American Journal of International  Law (v.88, 1994);
  2. Thomas Andersson, Multinational Investment  in Developing Countries:  A Study of Taxation  and Nationalization (Routledge, 1991);
  3. Lars Bengtsson, “Governmental Markets, Regulations, and Hierarchies: Building Trust in the  Face of Nationalization,” International  Studies of Management & Organization (v.23, 1993);
  4. Maurice Bye, “Self Financed Multi-Territorial Units and Their Time Horizon,” International Economic Papers (1958);
  5. Amy L. Chua, “Markets, Democracy, and Ethnicity: Toward a New Paradigm for Law and Development,” Yale Law Journal (1998);
  6. Fath El Rahman Abdalla El Sheikh, The Legal Regime of Foreign Private Investment in Sudan and Saudi Arabia (Cambridge University Press, 2003);
  7. Edith T. Penrose, The Growth of the Firm, Middle East Oil  and  Other  Essays (Frank  Cass, 1971);
  8. Edith T. Penrose, The Large International Firm in Developing Countries: The International Petroleum Industry (Allen and Unwin, 1968);
  9. David Schneiderman,  “Constitutional  Approaches  to Privatization: An Inquiry into the  Magnitude  of Neo-Liberal  Constitutionalism,” Law and  Contemporary  Problems (v.63, 2000);
  10. J. Stigler, “The Theory of Economic Regulation,” The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (1971).

This example Nationalization Essay is published for educational and informational purposes only. If you need a custom essay or research paper on this topic please use our writing services. EssayEmpire.com offers reliable custom essay writing services that can help you to receive high grades and impress your professors with the quality of each essay or research paper you hand in.

See also:

ORDER HIGH QUALITY CUSTOM PAPER


Always on-time

Plagiarism-Free

100% Confidentiality

Special offer!

GET 10% OFF WITH 24START DISCOUNT CODE