Open Economy Macroeconomics Essay

Cheap Custom Writing Service

 

Much  of the  influential  research  in macroeconomics in the post–Great Depression era has focused on domestic economic fluctuations. For a large country such as the United  States, the assumption  that  foreign interest  rates had little effect on domestic  economic  variables  was accepted.  Foreign  investment and net factor flows were small relative to the domestic economy. Furthermore, the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates ensured  that  little reason to model currency fluctuations existed. Today, however, understanding linkages between national economies is of critical importance.

The first step toward  a serious modeling of open economy macroeconomics came with the introduction  of the  Mundell-Fleming  model,  which was an improvement on the basic Keynesian IS-LM structure. Recently, scholars have developed more advanced models based on microeconomic foundations.  Some of these models are based on closed economy versions of equilibrium  models  of the  business  cycle. Other scholars have attempted to incorporate “sticky prices” into their models in the tradition  of New Keynesian macroeconomics.

Whatever the approach, it is crucial to realize that the basic challenges of open economy macroeconomics are that linkages exist between markets and must be respected,  and that  there  are limits to what government  policy can accomplish because they cannot control  all the variables simultaneously—a problem sometimes referred to as the trilemma.

Models

One possible reason that progress in open economy macroeconomics  began  rather   slowly  is  that   the United States, as the dominant  economy, was largely assumed to be able to pursue its own domestic policy objectives without regard for interest rates and other prices  in the  rest  of the  world. Hence,  research  in macroeconomics focused mainly on domestic prices and  interest  rates.  In the  Keynesian paradigm,  the overriding  objective was to  understand how active intervention with fiscal and  monetary  policy could promote economic stabilization.

One  basic approach  simply adds  net  exports  to the  Keynesian model.  Domestic  spending  (absorption) depends positively on domestic income and negatively on the domestic interest  rate. Net exports depend  positively on foreign income and negatively on domestic income. Real exchange-rate depreciation at home causes domestic  goods to become cheaper on the  world market  and, thus,  improves  the  trade balance. Putting  these statements  together  yields an open economy IS curve.

As a result,  for  example,  an  increase  in  foreign income  will increase  domestic  aggregate  demand, causing both  domestic  output  and  interest  rates  to increase. The amount  that  output  and interest  rates increase depends on the money market and whether the economy is near full employment.

The Mundell-Fleming  model builds on this approach by further specifying that in a world of perfect  capital  mobility  and  fixed exchange  rates,  the situation described above would result in an increase in domestic interest  rates relative to world rates and lead to increased capital inflows. The result is a balance-of-payments surplus. As foreign capital rushes in, upward pressure  is put on the value of domestic currency.  If the economy  is small (by definition, an economy that  cannot  affect world prices or interest rates), this pressure  would require  the central  bank to sell the domestic currency (buy foreign reserves). This action takes the pressure off, discouraging capital  inflows  and  bringing  the  balance  of  payments back into balance. As a result, of course, the domestic interest rate would fall back toward the world rate. In the case of perfect capital mobility and fixed exchange rates, the monetary  authority  of a small open economy is completely at the mercy of external factors.

The monetarist approach takes a somewhat different view. Whereas the Keynesian approach to macroeconomic stabilization policy puts more emphasis on fiscal policy, the monetarist school of thought (associated with Milton Friedman and the University of Chicago) asserts that the supply of money is an important determinant of the balance of payments. Key features of the monetarist approach  are that  a stable money demand function depends on domestic prices and income. The money supply consists of both the supply circulating in the economy and foreign reserves. Finally, purchasing  power  parity  holds, and  money supply equals money demand.

The consequence  of the  monetarist setup  of the model is that given foreign prices and domestic income,  money  demand  remains  constant.   Therefore, in a fixed-exchange-rate regime, a change in the domestic money supply leads to an equal and opposite change in foreign reserves. As a result, the monetary authority  need not  intervene  in the exchange market but can restore balance-of-payments equilibrium through monetary policy alone.

Both the Keynesian and monetarist approaches can be extended  to models of exchange-rate  determination under floating exchange-rate  regimes. Although these models did much to increase understanding of how international variables (e.g., exchange rates and balance of payments)  respond  to changes  in global economic  conditions,  they are not based on microeconomic principles. Recent research has focused on modeling international economic relationships, giving special attention to the microeconomic foundations.

Recent  Developments

Numerous  puzzles in open economy macroeconomics cannot  be resolved  in the  older  Keynesian and monetarist frameworks. Among those puzzles is why a home bias tends to exist in both trade in goods and in asset holdings. Another question is why consumption  growth  across countries  is less correlated  than standard macroeconomic theory would predict. These puzzles exist because economic models based on perfectly competitive  markets  and  rational  optimizing behavior by consumers  and firms predict more trade and economic integration than scholars observe. One branch  of open  economy  macroeconomic research has tried to explain these anomalies through  the use of dynamic macroeconomic models similar to those that have been employed to analyze domestic macroeconomic issues such as business cycles.

Some of these puzzles can be solved without resorting  to the assumption  of price stickiness. The home-bias problem can be partially explained by adding transaction  costs. The cost adds a friction that prevents  consumers  and  firms  from  fully optimizing. Models  based  on  microeconomic  foundations can often be constructed to enough precision so that they can be calibrated  to empirical  data and tested quantitatively.

Price anomalies such as the failure of purchasing power parity and the failure of the exchange rate to correlate  systematically with other  variables require more than just transaction  costs to explain. Nominal price rigidity (or sticky prices) may also be necessary.

Research in the new open economy macroeconomics  builds  on  previous  work  by incorporating price  rigidities.  The  Mundell-Fleming   model,  like other models in the Keynesian tradition, assumed an extreme form of price rigidity: prices were assumed to be fixed. In the new open economy macroeconomics, prices are not fixed by assumption  but are allowed to be somewhat fixed in the short run. Often, the mechanism by which the price rigidity occurs is based on microeconomic foundations.  Imperfect  competition and  price  discrimination  are  common   features  of such models. Menu costs and other mechanisms  for allowing prices to update slowly ensure that the model does not go immediately to the long-run equilibrium. As a result, pricing anomalies arise endogenously; as a result,  government  intervention in  currency  and money markets may have real economic effects.

Unanswered Questions

Many unanswered questions remain, and many important recent  economic  phenomena present  an ambitious agenda for open economy macroeconomic research. There is fundamental  agreement among the many  models  that  an  economy  cannot  simultaneously achieve price stability, exchange rate stability, and  perfect  capital  mobility—a situation  known  as the trilemma.

Until recently, China  achieved the  first two conditions  by controlling  capital flows. As the Chinese economy loosens the capital controls, China will lose its grip on either domestic prices (higher inflation) or the exchange rate (revaluation). What remains uncertain is the precise mechanism  by which internal and external prices will be affected.

Other  economies face decisions about whether to abandon fixed exchange rate regimes to regain control of their domestic money supply. Fixed exchange rates offer stability but  are subject  to speculative  attack. Understanding  the  nature  of  nominal  price  rigidity in international markets  is crucial to evaluating the various policy options available to governments. Researchers in open economy macroeconomics continue to grapple with these critical issues.

Bibliography: 

  1. Malin Adolfson, Stefan Laséen, Jesper Lindé, and Mattias Villani, Evaluating an Estimated  New Keynesian Small  Open Economy Model (Centre  for Economic Policy Research, 2007);
  2. Paul R. Bergin, “How Well Can the  New Open  Economy  Macroeconomics  Explain the Exchange Rate and Current  Account?” Journal of International Money and Finance (v.25/5, 2006);
  3. Giancarlo Corsetti,  New  Open  Economy  Macroeconomics  (Centre for  Economic   Policy  Research,  2007);
  4. Rudiger  Dornbusch, Stanley Fischer, and Richard Startz, Macroeconomics (McGraw-Hill Irwin, 2008);
  5. Steven L. Husted and Michael Melvin, International Economics (Pearson  Addison-Wesley, 2007);
  6. Yongseung Jung, “Can the New Open Economy Macroeconomic  Model Explain Exchange Rate Fluctuations?” Journal of International  Economics (v.72/2, 2007);
  7. Paul Krugman, The Return of Depression Economics (W. W. Norton, 2000);
  8. C. Lim and Paul D. McNelis, Computational Macroeconomics  for the  Open  Economy (MIT Press, 2008);
  9. Maurice  Obstfeld, Jay C. Shambaugh, and Alan M. Taylor, “The Trilemma  in History: Tradeoffs Among  Exchange Rates, Monetary  Policies, and  Capital Mobility,” The Review of Economics and Statistics (v.87/3, 2005);
  10. Ozge Senay, “Interest Rate Rules and  Welfare  in Open  Economies,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy (v.55/3, July 2008).

This example Open Economy Macroeconomics Essay is published for educational and informational purposes only. If you need a custom essay or research paper on this topic please use our writing services. EssayEmpire.com offers reliable custom essay writing services that can help you to receive high grades and impress your professors with the quality of each essay or research paper you hand in.

See also:

ORDER HIGH QUALITY CUSTOM PAPER


Always on-time

Plagiarism-Free

100% Confidentiality

Special offer!

GET 10% OFF WITH 24START DISCOUNT CODE